Disclaimer: I am now retired, and am therefore no longer
an expert on anything. This blog post
presents only my opinions, and anything in it should not be relied on.
Over the past few days, I have been reading Kim Stanley
Robinson’s “Green Earth” trilogy, an examination of possible futures and
strategies in dealing with climate change thinly disguised as science
fiction. One phrase in it struck me with
especial force: “the blind hand of the
market never picks up the check.” To put
it in more economic terms:
·
Firms, and therefore market economies as a
whole, typically seek profit maximization, and because the path to profit from
new investment is always uncertain, to focus particularly on cost minimization
within a chosen, relatively conservative profit-maximization strategy.
·
To minimize costs, they may not only use new
technologies (productivity enhancement), but also offload costs as far as
possible onto other firms, consumers, workers, societies, and governments. Of these, the most difficult is offloading
costs onto other firms (e.g., via supply-chain management), since these are
also competing to minimize their costs and therefore to offload right
back. Therefore, especially for the large,
global firms that dominate today’s markets, the name of the game is to not only
minimize costs from workers, consumers (consider help desks as an example), and
societies/governments, but also to get “subsidies” from these (time flexibility
or overtime from workers, consumers performing more of the work of [and bearing
more of the risk of] the sales transaction, governments not only providing
subsidies but also things such as infrastructure support, education and
training of the work force, and dealing with natural disasters – now including
climate change).
Often, especially in regard to climate change, economists
may refer to the process of the invisible hand never picking up the check as
the “tragedy of the commons.” The flaw
of this analysis is to limit one’s gaze implicitly to tangible property. If one uses as a broader metric money
equivalents, then it is clear that it is not just “common goods” that are being
raided, but personal non-goods such as worker/consumer/neither time that
translates to poorer health and less ability to cope with life’s demands,
sapping productivity directly as well as via its effects on the worker/consumer’s
support system, not to mention the government’s ability to compensate as it is
starved of money. And all of this still
does not capture the market’s ability to “game the system” by monopolizing
government and the law.
Another point also struck me when I read this phrase: macroeconomics does not even begin to measure
the amount of that “cost raiding”, instead referring to it as “externalities”. And therefore:
Economics cannot say whether market capitalism is better than other
approaches, or worse, or the same. It
cannot say anything at all on the subject.
Further Thoughts About Economics and Alternatives to Market Capitalism
A further major flaw, imho, in economics’ approach to the
whole subject is the idea that cost minimization should not only be a desired
end but also the major goal of an enterprise.
I am specifically thinking of the case of the agile company. As I have mentioned before, agile software development
deemphasizes cost, quality, revenue, time to market, and profit in favor of
constantly building in flexibility to adjust to and anticipate the changing
needs of the consumer. And yet, agile
development outperforms approaches that do concentrate on these metrics by 25%
at a minimum and sometimes 100%.
If the entire economy were based on real agile firms, I would suggest that we would see a comparable
improvement in the economy – permanently.
Moreover, the focus on the consumer should lead to a diminution in “cost
raiding”. The focus on being truly in
tune with the consumer’s needs, for example, should diminish raiding the
consumer’s time in the sales transaction and forcing them to use the help-desk
bottleneck. And I still live in hope
that agile development with fewer time constraints will empower the developer
with the ability to seek out and implement his or her own tools to improve processes,
thereby allowing better retraining.
Implications of Climate Change for Economics and Market Capitalism
Robinson includes a critique of market capitalism in his
work, and concludes that it has to change fundamentally. I find the critique itself problematic; but
that doesn’t mean he isn’t right in his conclusion.
The fundamental question to me is, what happens when
externalities go in reverse, and suddenly the things that have led to ongoing
profits lead to ongoing losses? Robinson
paints a frightening picture of a world in which brownouts, blackouts, killing
cold, and killing heat are common, and insurance, whether private or
governmental, cannot adequately compensate, leading additional costs to settle,
inexorably, on their last resort, business.
Then, implicitly, firms must cannibalize each other, with the largest
being best equipped to do so.
I tend to place things in less apocalyptic terms. According to Prof. deLong, GDP performance
can be thought of as part improvement in productivity and part expansion of the
workforce. The climate change scenario
necessarily implies a shrinkage of that workforce (in labor-hours) faster than
productivity can climb, and therefore a constantly shrinking market. In that case, the market’s rising need for “cost
raiding” as the market shrinks simply speeds up the shrinkage of the market –
not to mention the underlying societies.
And that, to me, is the fundamental flaw that needs correcting.
Theoretically, one option is to capture things like “the
social cost of carbon” in company accounting – an idea I wrote about five years
ago. Practically speaking, the uneven
effects of that on companies mean real impact on the employees of coal and oil
companies, a fact we have already seen a small foretaste of, and that has further
revealed the ability of oil and coal companies to entirely snarl the political
process to prevent adequate steps at limiting “cost raiding” – and that makes
our carbon pricing efforts in real-world terms more likely than not to be
inadequate to reverse the “cost raiding” trend.
The obvious alternative, which I and others have argued for
and I in fact picked up on eight years ago when I first understood the dire
implications of climate change, is “World War II in America”, governmental
interference in the economy comparable to that of WWII in order to “win the war
on climate change”. Only, of course, the
aim is to lose the war with as little damage as possible. So suppose we do that; what then?
The obvious answer is, “sustainability” – meaning practices
that will ensure that having “won the war”, we don’t lose it again in the future
by slipping back into the old carbon-guzzling, ecology-devastating, arable-land-destroying
habits. Is that enough? Robinson says no, that despite
sustainability, cost raiding will continue to increase in other areas. And here I tend to agree with him, although I
am not sure.
It appears, reverting to Prof. deLong’s point above, that it
is possible with sustainability to continue to improve both human welfare and
corporate profitability, by improving productivity with a more or less stable
(almost certainly shrunken) population and workforce. However, productivity improvement may well be
less than in the Industrial Revolution – it has already slowed for an unduly
long time. And if that is the case, then
there is no market-capitalism path forward that involves today’s increases in
corporate profitability and avoids cost raiding increases.
I don’t know the answer to this. I feel, however, that the beginnings of an
answer lie not in perpetually increasing the size of the workforce by improving
human welfare, while somehow not increasing population, but rather in
perpetually increasing “consumer productivity”:
the value that people get out of their lives, that they can then invest
in others. More specifically, I think
markets can be divided into those for carrying out daily tasks (“Do”), those
for socializing and participating in society (“Socialize”) and those for
learning and creating (“Learn”). A
balance must be kept between these efforts in any individual’s life, so the
perpetual increases must be achieved inside each of these three sets of
markets.
I would argue that today’s market economies use “Do” to crowd
out much of the other two sets of markets, and are less good at perpetually
increasing the value of “Socialize” and “Learn”, although the crowding-out may
mean that “Do”’s superiority is illusory.
I have no clear idea as to what to do about my conclusions, except to
examine each set of markets more closely to gain clues as to how to achieve
this perpetual value increase.
Just some thoughts.
And oh, by the way, Robinson is indeed worth reading.